• Tools and Resources
  • Customer Services
  • Econometrics, Experimental and Quantitative Methods
  • Economic Development
  • Economic History
  • Economic Theory and Mathematical Models
  • Environmental, Agricultural, and Natural Resources Economics
  • Financial Economics
  • Health, Education, and Welfare Economics
  • History of Economic Thought
  • Industrial Organization
  • International Economics
  • Labor and Demographic Economics
  • Law and Economics
  • Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics
  • Micro, Behavioral, and Neuro-Economics
  • Public Economics and Policy
  • Urban, Rural, and Regional Economics
  • Share This Facebook LinkedIn Twitter

Article contents

Economic geography and trade.

  • Anthony J. Venables Anthony J. Venables Department of Economics, University of Oxford
  • https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.332
  • Published online: 25 February 2019

Economic activity is unevenly distributed across space, both internationally and within countries. What determines this spatial distribution, and how is it shaped by trade? Classical trade theory gives the insights of comparative advantage and gains from trade but is firmly aspatial, modeling countries as points and trade (in goods and factors of production) as either perfectly frictionless or impossible. Modern theory places this in a spatial context in which geographical considerations influence the volume of trade between places. Gravity models tell us that distance is important, with each doubling of distance between places halving the volume of trade. Modeling the location decisions of firms gives a theory of location of activity based on factor costs (as in classical theory) and also on proximity to markets, proximity to suppliers, and the extent of competition in each market. It follows from this that—if there is a high degree of mobility—firms and economic activity as a whole may tend to cluster, providing an explanation of observed spatial unevenness. In some circumstances falling trade barriers may trigger the deindustrialization of some areas as activity clusters in fewer places. In other circumstances falling barriers may enable activity to spread out, reducing inequalities within and between countries. Research over the past several decades has established the mechanisms that cause these changes and placed them in full general equilibrium models of the economy. Empirical work has quantified many of the important relationships. However, geography and trade remains an area where progress is needed to develop robust tools that can be used to inform place-based policies (concerning trade, transport, infrastructure, and local economic development), particularly in view of the huge expenditures that such policies incur.

  • economic geography
  • globalization
  • agglomeration

Introduction

Spatial unevenness is a striking characteristic of the world economy. Per capita income levels vary across countries by a factor of more than 100 to 1: within countries population and economic activity concentrate in cities that cover a small fraction of the national land area: global activity in some sectors—finance, high-tech, film-making—is concentrated in relatively few cities. Some of this is explained by physical geography, but most of it is the outcome of economic processes. Textbook economic principles offer no explanation of this unevenness; under the standard assumptions of general equilibrium theory economic activity will tend to smear more or less uniformly across space. A recent literature combining insights from economic geography and from trade theory does offer an explanation, showing how trade may create spatial structures that are highly uneven. Relatively uniform distribution of activity may not be a (stable) equilibrium as clustering occurs.

This article reviews the theory and the implications that flow from it. The central question to be addressed is: What determines the location of economic activity? The question can be posed at different spatial levels: location across nations, across regions, across cities, or within a particular city. And it can be posed of different economic variables: the location of people or the location of jobs, in aggregate or in different sectors. The answer is important because the spatial distribution of income and prosperity follows from it. This article focuses on the international angle and on why some places are more attractive locations for production—and hence offer higher wages and incomes—than others.

As usual in economics, the fundamental determinants are endowments, technology, and preferences. At a point in space these are natural resources, stocks of labor and capital, available technologies and institutions, and the preferences of inhabitants. Trade and economic geography bring the extra ingredient of spatial interaction, determined by the mobility of factors of production, technology, and the goods and services that they produce. The spatial scale of mobility varies, with labor moving freely within a country but generally not between countries; capital flows between countries but is often subject to regulation; the mobility of goods and services spans the spectrum from instantaneous global transmission of digital products to nontradable supply of haircuts and restaurant meals. The impact of these spatial interactions depends on the economic environment in which they occur. Ideas can move quite freely, but the absorptive capacity of a firm or country to employ them varies widely. The effect of integrating separate national goods or service markets depends on characteristics of the regions that are integrating and of the sectors that are being integrated.

The tasks facing researchers in economic geography and trade are therefore twofold: (a) to understand the form and extent of spatial interactions—what is mobile, what is immobile, and why? and (b) to understand the implications of these interactions for the spatial distribution of activity and prosperity, recognizing the heterogeneity of types of interaction and of the economic environments in which they occur.

Partial answers to these questions come from the classic models of international trade dating back to Ricardo and the works of Heckscher and Ohlin. These models (at least in their current textbook form, e.g., Krugman, Obstfeld, & Melitz, 2015 ) concentrate on trade in final goods, trade being driven by international differences in technology (Ricardo), or endowments (Heckscher-Ohlin). These models give us the key insights of comparative advantage and the gains from trade. However, they have no geography—countries are “points,” and mobility is either assumed to be perfect (frictionless trade in goods) or impossible (factor assumed immobile). 1 The economic environment of these models is one of constant returns to scale and perfect competition. These assumptions limit the set of questions that can be addressed and also mean that the approach offers little insight into three predominant features of trade and economic geography: (a) most international trade flows are curtailed sharply by distance, (b) intra-industry trade is present (two-way trade flows in similar products between similar economies), and (c) spatial unevenness exists in economic activity.

Developments in economic geography and trade have gone a long way to fill these gaps. The “new” trade theory of the 1980s adds imperfect competition and increasing returns, focusing attention on the behavior of firms. This provides a theory of intra-industry trade and also a framework in which to analyze the location decisions of firms. Building on this it became apparent that sufficiently high levels of spatial interaction—or, to put it crudely, sufficiently many things being mobile—create the possibility that economic activity will tend to concentrate in relatively few places. In some circumstances trade is a driver of convergence between places, and in others it causes divergence and creates spatial unevenness.

This article provides a selective overview of this literature and the main results and insights that come from it. The overview is nontechnical, giving references to previously published technical surveys. The next section deals with the geographical pattern of trade flows; it is largely empirical but establishes the point that geography matters for trade. The following section turns to theory, outlining a basic model of location of “industry.” Here the term “industry” is used to cover productive activities whose location is not fixed by dependence on natural resources (agriculture or mining) or by servicing geographically fixed assets (e.g., provision of utilities); the term therefore applies to manufacturing and large parts of the service sector. Following this applications of the theory and empirics are discussed, finally turning to directions for future research.

The Geography of Trade

The point of departure for studying economic geography and trade is to look at the economic geography of trade. The overwhelming feature is that trade flows are sharply curtailed by distance. Thus, the UK trades more with Ireland than it does with China, an economy 50 times larger. Geography and spatial frictions evidently matter for trade, and the tool for researching them is the “gravity model,” first written down by Jan Tinbergen in 1962 . Stripped down to essentials, it says that the value of trade between two countries is approximated by the relationship

where X ij are the exports from i to j ; d ij are “between-country” characteristics, in particular the distance between the two countries; Z i are exporter country characteristics; and Z j are importer country features. A relationship of this type is consistent with a number of theoretical underpinnings, providing that there are some trade frictions between countries and some reason for trade. 2

There is good data on bilateral goods trade between most countries in the world, so this relationship can be econometrically estimated. The simplest form is to assume the relationship is log-linear and use distance as the only between-country variable and gross domestic product (GDP) as the exporter and importer country characteristics. A thorough exposition of these models, the technical issues involved, and the main results are discussed in Head and Mayer ( 2014 ), on which following paragraphs draw.

The coefficients on income are generally close to unity, and the coefficient on distance is close to –1. 3 This implies that the effects of distance are large: trade volumes are proportional to the reciprocal of distance so each doubling of distance halves the volume of trade (conditional on GDP). The relationship is typically estimated on aggregate goods trade and across a wide range of countries, so coefficients are average effects. These mask a lot of heterogeneity—trade in oil is quite different from trade in motor vehicle parts. Estimating the relationship for service trade is hard, as bilateral service trade data is not widely available, although estimates suggest that the effect of distance is only slightly less for services than for goods trade. There are some estimates of Internet trade, giving estimates of the gravity coefficient about two-thirds that of corresponding trade flows (Lendle, Olarreaga, Schropp, & Vézina, 2016 ).

Many other variables have been added to the minimal version sketched earlier. Additional between-country measures include contiguity (+, indicating more trade), common language (+), colonial relationship (+), membership of a common regional integration agreement (+), and common currency (+). Further measures of exporter and importer country characteristics include land area (–) and division of aggregate GDP into population and per capita GDP, both positive and the latter larger than the former.

Finally, there is evidence that the absolute value of the distance coefficient has increased over time, rising from around 0.95 in the 1970s to around 1.1 in recent studies (Disdier & Head, 2008 ). This seems surprising, particularly in view of popular writings on the death of distance (e.g., Cairncross, 1997 ), but it should be borne in mind that this is a slope coefficient and the intercept of the relationship was increasing through most of the period; trade was increasing relative to GDP, but long-distance trade increased less rapidly than short distance.

These findings all indicate substantial geographical trade frictions. What underpins them? Numerous mechanisms can be posited, although empirical study has not been successful in establishing the relative importance of each. Transport costs are the most obvious. Research suggests that the elasticity of transport costs with respect to distance is less than unity while the elasticity of trade with respect to transport costs is greater than unity (absolute value), these combining to give the trade/distance coefficient of –1. Time in transit is important and has probably become more so with the rise of international production networks. The importance of just-in-time delivery in these and other trades is put forward as one reason for the increase in the absolute value of the distance coefficient through time. Perhaps the most important factor, if hard to quantity, is a package of costs of doing business at a distance. Firms and traders are likely to have better information about nearby markets than remote ones, it is easier transacting in similar time zones, face-to-face contact is important for building trust in relationships, and so on.

The Location of Activity: Theory

Geography matters for trade, and trade matters for shaping economic geography. To capture this a theory of location of economic activity is needed. Classical trade theory offers a theory, but, as noted earlier, its assumptions proved too restrictive to provide insight into many important phenomena. In particular, the rise in the volume of intra-industry trade that occurred in the postwar period is not readily explained by models of trade under perfect competition. This fact, together with the increasing returns revolution in economic theory that took place in the 1980s, led to a change in the focus of trade theory with the “new trade theory.”

The new trade theory consists of several ingredients, of which the most important is the focus on firms. Firms are modeled as having economies of scale (this giving them finite size and implying marginal cost below average cost); as having some market power, so able to price above marginal cost; and typically deriving this market power from product differentiation, modeled in the style pioneered by Dixit and Stiglitz ( 1977 ). Production sectors are typically modelled as monopolistically competitive (i.e., with the number of constituent firms determined by free entry/exit until a zero profit condition is satisfied). The approach provides a fertile framework for addressing numerous issues. Intra-industry trade arises naturally as each firm can make profit by selling its product in each market. Such trade is consistent with the gravity relationship as, given likely price elasticities of demand for the products of particular firms, quite small trade frictions have a large impact on trade volumes. The framework enabled rich seams of work on foreign direct investment (Markusen, 2002 ) and on firm level heterogeneity, the latter using micro-level datasets (Melitz & Redding, 2014 ).

The approach also provides a framework for analyzing firms’ location decisions and hence the economic geography of trade and production. The different forces at work can be illustrated for a single industry in a simple reduced form framework. A single firm in country i has sales volume in country j expressed as X i j = f ( d i j , c i , m j ) . Sales decrease with distance, d ij , and with costs of production in country i , c i , since both of these increase the price of goods supplied from i to j . However, they are an increasing function of the “market capacity” of country j market, denoted m j . Market capacity is the size of the country j market (expenditure in the sector under study) combined (inversely) with a measure of market crowdedness, that is, the competitive pressure from other firms that supply this market. 4

The total sales of a country i firm across all markets are x i = ∑ j f ( d i j , c i , m j ) and, in models of this type, each firm breaks even if sales reach a particular level, x ¯ , making positive profits if sales exceed this and losses if they are less. 5 The number of firms in country i is denoted n i , and the monopolistic competition setting means that there is entry of country i firms, denoted Δ n i > 0 , if profits are positive, and exit, Δ n i < 0 , if firms are loss making, so

Equilibrium is when the number of firms has adjusted such that Δ n i = 0 for all i .

The mechanisms that bring about this equality are dependence of costs c i and market capacity m j on the number of firms, n i . 6 The remainder of this section outlines four forces that drive this dependency and hence ensure that equation ( 2 ) is equal to zero.

Factor Costs

The first mechanism—and that akin to classical trade theory—is that factor prices and costs of production in the country are increasing in the scale of operation of the industry, so c i is increasing in n i . Thus the scale of activity in country i , as represented by the number of firms, n i , increases until wages and costs are bid up to the point where no further entry is profitable. This obviously depends on the size, productivity, and elasticity of supply of factors of production used in country i .

Market Size and Market Crowding

Entry of firms will not only bid up factor prices in the producing country but also increase supply and therefore reduce prices in markets to which they export. Thus market capacity m j is a decreasing function of the number of firms in each of the countries that export to country j . 7 If all countries are identical the solution is easy to see. The same number of firms operates in each country, and the number is such that factor prices and output prices have jointly adjusted to make equation ( 2 ) equal to zero.

What if countries are not symmetric? If one country is α ‎% larger than another, one might guess that it has α ‎% more firms, and this would be correct if each country’s firms took the same share of each market. But if there are trade frictions and gravity holds, then firms have a larger share of their home market than of their export markets. The larger country must then have more than α ‎% of the world’s firms, as its firms have the largest share in the largest market. This is sometimes referred to as the home market effect, and it means that large centers (in different contexts large cities, regions, or countries) are advantaged by the geography of gravity. The advantage takes some combination of larger countries having disproportionately more firms and, if factor prices are increasing in the number of firms, also having higher wages and higher real incomes. Empirical support for this effect is discussed later. 8

Factor Mobility

A further mechanism comes into play if factors of production—labor in particular—are mobile between places. The home market effect discussed in the previous paragraph suggests that a large country might have higher wages and real incomes. Labor mobility attracts immigrants, further enlarging the size of the market (tending to increase market capacity, m i ) and perhaps also mitigating increasing factor costs (reducing c i ). If this effect is strong enough then the right-hand side of equation ( 2 ) becomes an increasing function of the number of firms n i , so that having more firms creates a force for attracting still more. This mechanism is the driver of the “core-periphery” model of Krugman ( 1991b ). The simplest version of this model has two regions that are identical in their underlying structure and parameters and some workers and firms that are mobile between regions. Symmetry of structure and parameters means that there is always a symmetric equilibrium with the same number of firms in each region, but this may be unstable—if one region becomes slightly larger it will attract firms and migrants and become still larger. In addition to the unstable symmetric equilibrium, there are therefore two asymmetric equilibria, in which all firms have moved to either one region or the other. The model provides no prediction as to which might occur but makes the fundamental point that spatial interactions can create divergence in economic outcomes between places that have identical economic fundamentals.

Linkages, Intermediate Goods, and Clusters

The combination of the home market effect and labor mobility create the possibility that the right-hand side of (2) is increasing in n i . Other mechanisms, perhaps more relevant in the international context, can have the same effect. One such mechanism is the presence of intermediate goods, produced under conditions of product differentiation and monopolistic competition (Venables, 1996 ). More firms in a place mean a larger market for intermediate goods (a backwards linkage creating a larger market capacity, m i for suppliers of intermediates). This attracts firms that supply intermediate goods, and proximity of suppliers to users brings a cost reduction (a forward linkage creating a lower c i ) for firms using the goods. This reinforces the attractiveness of the place for final goods production setting off the process of cumulative causation and clustering of industry in one place.

This is one example of a wider set of agglomeration economies that are generated by close and intense economic interaction and have the effect of raising productivity in affected areas and activities. They arise through several different mechanisms. 9 Thick labor markets enable better matching of workers to firms’ skill requirements. Better communication between firms and their customers and suppliers enables knowledge spillovers, better product design, and timely production. A larger local market enables development of a larger network or more specialized suppliers. Fundamentally, larger and denser markets allow for both scale and specialization. A good example is given by specialist workers or suppliers. The larger the market, the more likely it is to be worthwhile for an individual to specialize and hone skills in producing a particular good or service. The presence of highly specialized skills will raise overall productivity. The specialist will be paid for the product or service supplied but, depending on market conditions, is unlikely to capture the full benefit created. 10 Since the benefit is split between the supplier and his or her customers, there is a positive externality. And this creates a positive feedback—more firms will be attracted to the place to receive the benefit, growing the market, further increasing the returns to specialization, and so on. This is the classic process of cluster formation.

These mechanisms have both a spatial and a sectoral range. They may be sector specific, tied to particular labor skills, firm capabilities, or input-output linkage (in which case they are sometimes referred to as “localization” or “Marshall-Romer” economies), or they may operate across many sectors (in the regional economics literature referred to as “urbanization” or “Jacobs” economies). They are developed rigorously in the literature, being given micro-economic foundations and set in a full general equilibrium framework in which not only the determinants but also the full implications of location choices are established.

In sum, economic geography and trade gives a theory of industrial location determined by four mechanisms:

Factor costs, in turn a function of endowments and technology.

Market access, trade costs, proximity, market size, and market crowding.

Supplier access and agglomeration and proximity to suppliers of intermediate goods and other complementary activities or sources of technological spillovers.

Factor mobility: the mobility of factors of production, feeding back to influence endowments and market size.

The first of these is the subject of classic trade theory, and the second adds trade frictions and gravity. Together they imply diminishing returns to expanding activity and hence unique and stable equilibria. The third and fourth are at the center of economic geography. They create positive feedbacks and hence the potential for multiple equilibria and the clustering of economic activity. 11

Issues and Applications

The approaches outlined in the preceding section have been applied to a number of issues, three of which are outlined in this section, starting with international inequalities, turning to emergent structure, and ending with trade and economic development.

Trade and International Inequalities

A central concern of much work in economic geography has been imbalance between successful and lagging regions. This may be within countries or, in the international context, shaping global inequalities and economic development. Central questions are: How does openness to trade affect international inequalities? In what circumstances do some countries benefit from trade while others lose, in relative or absolute terms?

The simplest economic geography framework for addressing this question is a world containing two countries, and, to address the question in its purest form, the countries are assumed to have identical fundamentals. 12 Each country has a single factor of production (labor, which is internationally immobile) and may potentially have activity in two sectors. One is perfectly competitive, operates under constant returns to scale, and is freely traded. The other is an industrial sector, monopolistically competitive as sketched in the previous section. This sector also has the feature that its output is used both as final consumer goods and as intermediates in the same sector. Thus inputs to “industry” are both labor and industrial products, and the output of industry is partly for final consumption and partly intermediate inputs for industry. 13 What happens as the cost of trading industrial goods between countries are reduced?

This is a model in which mechanisms 2 and 3 of the previous list operate but mechanisms 1 and 4 are switched off. This captures the “fundamental trade-off in spatial economics,” between costs of mobility and various types of scale economies (Fujita & Thisse, 2002 ). Mechanism 2 is a force for dispersion of activity; given that there are consumers in both countries and trade costs, firms want to locate in both countries. Mechanism 3 is a force for concentration and clustering; firms want to be close to supplier firms and customer firms. How does the balance change as trade barriers are reduced?

At prohibitively high trade costs industry must be located in both countries in order to meet the demands of consumers so, if the countries have identical fundamentals, the equilibrium will be symmetric, with production equally divided and both economies identical. As trade costs are reduced so there is intra-industry trade and consumers and producers (users of intermediate goods) gain from importing foreign industrial varieties and from the potential for exports. The symmetric outcome remains an equilibrium, but there are two critical levels of trade costs at which bifurcation of equilibrium takes place. These are illustrated in Figure 1a , which has the share of industrial employment in each country’s labor force on the vertical axis and trade frictions on the horizontal. At critical value T(S) two further equilibria emerge, one with country 1 specialized in industry ( λ ‎ 1 = 1) and country 2 retaining a lower level of industrial employment (1 > λ ‎ 2 ≥ 0) and the other symmetric (i.e., with country labels reversed). The reason is that, as outlined earlier, intermediate goods create an agglomeration force, with firms in an agglomeration benefitting from forward linkages (many suppliers in the same place) and backwards linkages (much local intermediate demand for their output).

The second critical value is T(B), the point of symmetry breaking. At trade costs lower than this, the symmetric equilibrium is unstable (and therefore indicated by a dashed line). If one country has just slightly more industry than the other, then it is profitable for further firms to move into this country, amplifying the difference between them. In the simplest model T(S) > T(B) and in the interval between these values there are five equilibria, three of them stable and two (the curved dashed lines) unstable.

Figure 1b gives the corresponding real wages in each country, ω ‎ i , relative to world average real wages (illustrated just for stable equilibria where country 1 has industry). Evidently, clustering of industry in one place creates international inequalities. The divergence of income levels reaches a maximum, beyond which further reductions in trade costs bring convergence of incomes, although not of economic structure. The reason is that, in this example, both the dispersion and concentration forces (mechanisms 2 and 3) are assumed to operate only via trade costs, so as these costs go to zero so too does their effect. In the limit of perfectly free trade (T = 1), the location of industry becomes indeterminate, and all prices and incomes are the same in both countries (factor price equalization).

How is this picture altered if other locations mechanisms are brought into play? Other agglomeration mechanisms (e.g., better labor market matching or skill development) increase the likelihood of agglomeration and makes it less dependent on trade costs, T. Thus, even with perfectly free trade, labor market forces might lead clusters to be persistent. Migration (mechanism 4) further increases the likelihood of clustering of activity as it tends to make large markets larger (the home market effect and core-periphery model). Migration may also operate by creating larger pools of labor—particularly skilled labor—in existing centers of activity. Pushing in the other direction are immobile factors and the fact that centers of activity will have relatively high prices of such factors. In the urban context this is high land rents, and internationally it is high wages and labor costs.

The structure of equilibria outlined here is radically different from that of classical trade theory and provides alternative insights into the effects of trade. At its broadest, it gives insight into the rise and fall of international inequalities, from the great divergence (the rise of international inequalities following northern Europe’s industrialization and the accompanying deindustrialization of parts of Asia) through to the geographical spread of industry that has emerged during the era of globalization.

Figure 1a. International inequalities; the location of industry. Based on Fujita et al. ( 1999 , pp. 253–254).

Notes : T: Trade cost factor; free trade where T = 1.

λ ‎ i : Share of country i labor force in industry, i = 1, 2.

Figure 1b. International inequalities; relative real wages. Based on Fujita et al. ( 1999 , pp. 253–254).

ω ‎ i : Real wage in country i relative to global average, i = 1, 2.

Trade, Geography, and Emergent Structure

The preceding subsection took an example of a two-country world, with just two sectors of activity. What does the structure of equilibria look like more generally? With many locations and clustering forces operating (in particular sectors and perhaps also in aggregate), we expect to see industrial activity concentrated in a subset of locations, with other places dependent on their natural resource (e.g., agricultural) base. The question then becomes: What is the size and shape of these clusters of activity? Are they high frequency (e.g., industrial activity in lots of small villages) or low frequency (e.g., concentrated in one or two locations from which they serve the world)? To address these questions Fujita, Krugman, and Venables ( 1999 ) apply an approach from the classic work of Turing ( 1952 ) on morphogenesis.

The starting point is “flat earth”—a situation in which economic activity is smeared uniformly across space. If all points are identical (in fundamentals and outcomes), then this is an equilibrium, although it may be unstable. If so, slight perturbation will cause structure to emerge from the homogenous starting point as the system moves to an asymmetric equilibrium. The size and frequency of clusters that form at this frequency have a distinct eigenvalue, determined by parameters that drive the dynamic adjustment process. Thus in simple cases it can be shown that if trade costs are high and agglomeration forces weak, there will be high-frequency clustering (i.e., numerous small clusters of activity). Lower trade costs and/or stronger agglomeration leads to low-frequency outcomes, with fewer but larger centers. Increasing the share of immobile factors of production (whose prices are determined by demand at each point, rather than being set through international arbitrage) also leads to low-frequency outcomes and, if the share is large enough, will prevent clusters from forming at all.

These results are derived by starting, for each set of parameters, from “flat-earth.” What happens if the starting point is an established pattern of clusters? The thought experiment is to suppose an initial situation of high-frequency clusters (established with high trade costs) and investigate what happens as trade costs are reduced. The answer is that the structure is robust over a wide range of trade costs, and only when a critical value of costs is reached does spatial structure reorganise to a lower frequency pattern. If the change was occurring through time, the pattern would be one of punctuated equilibria: long periods of stability punctuated by periods of radical spatial reorganization as existing clusters unravel and new ones become established.

The robustness of a given spatial structure derives from several forces. One is the rents of agglomeration. An established center has high productivity and hence an advantage over other places. In equilibrium the advantage is captured by immobile factors—land in the case of cities, labor in the international context. Small changes may squeeze these rents but not to the point where they cease to be profitable to operate. This argument is amplified by the fact that capital—buildings but also human capital in sector specific skills—is sunk in existing centers, as is earning quasi-rents. The other side of this coin is the difficulty of establishing new activities in new places, which creates obstacles to economic development.

Economic Development and Coordination Failure

Agglomeration forces are generally driven by economies of scale that are external to individual economic agents (firms or workers) but internal to a place, which, depending on context, may be a district within a city, a wider region, or a country as a whole. This externality creates a “first-mover problem” and means that it is hard to start an activity in a new place. If a place has the activity, then agglomeration benefits mean that productivity is high enough for the place to be competitive (even at relatively high wages). If the place does not have the activity, then the productivity of a potential entrant is low, so entry is deterred. Coordinated action by many firms could achieve scale, but coordination failure may mean that the place remains trapped in a low-level equilibrium.

This problem is fundamental for the regeneration of areas of a city, for policy toward lagging regions, and for structural transformation in developing economies. For example, a developing economy may be accumulating factors of production and technology and acquiring a potential comparative advantage in new sectors. However, in the absence of existing activity, productivity is low, it is not profitable for any single firm to enter, and this potential comparative advantage is not realized. This coordination failure means that development of such sectors will commence later than is efficient and that there is scope for policy intervention. This argument formed the basis of “big-push” models of economic development (Hirschman, 1958 ; Murphy, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1989 ) and for policies that promote linkages between related sectors (Hausmann & Hidalgo, 2009 ; Myrdal, 1957 ).

For practical purposes, the sectoral scope of agglomeration effects is important. Trade liberalization and falling transport costs have enabled the development of global production networks in which a particular country (or city) specializes in a narrow part of the production process, sometimes referred to as “task specialization.” 14 Such narrowly defined tasks may have an extreme factor intensity (e.g., be very unskilled labor intensive), so that factor cost differentials are particularly important in location decisions. Furthermore, it is easier for countries to achieve scale in production of narrow tasks than it is to gain scale and productivity across a whole sector or range of sectors. Thus a development path has been to create jobs through clusters of activity in sectors such as ready-made garments (employing 4 million people in Bangladesh, clustered around Dhaka), electronic components, or assembly. However, global production networks have their own economic geography. They form between countries that have both significant factor cost differences and proximity (i.e., within East Asia and between the United States and Mexico). And they are spatially uneven, as agglomeration economies have concentrated them in particular places. Coordination failure matters even at this fine task level and has made it hard for new centers to become established, as witnessed by the numerous special economic zones that have been created around the world but that have failed to achieve this objective.

Empirical Studies

Agglomeration economies are a key mechanism in generating unevenness. There are many studies of the effect of economic scale and density on productivity, often undertaken on city-level data, and the first raw finding is that the elasticity of productivity with respect to city size is of the order of 0.05 to 0.1. Thus, a city of 5 million inhabitants typically has productivity 12% to 26% higher than a city of half a million. This raw number has been refined in many directions. 15 For example, the skill and occupational mix of the labor force varies across cities, impacting on measured productivity. Controlling for observed measures of skill (e.g., education) typically brings the elasticity down by about a quarter. This might only be part of the story, as there may be sorting, meaning that people with higher innate ability (regardless of education) are disproportionately drawn to cities. The only way to observe this is to track individuals as they move into cities or between cities of different sizes. Recent empirical work suggests that the pure agglomeration effect has elasticity of 0.02 to 0.04 (Combes & Gobillon, 2015 ). This is still a substantial number. 16

Estimates can be produced by sector and indicate that productivity effects are largest in high-tech sectors and business services. Corresponding to this, sectoral clustering is apparent in many sectors (ranging from financial services and films to the production of buttons). 17 The extent of clustering at the sectoral level has been demonstrated by authors including Ellison and Glaeser ( 1997 ), who show that many U.S. industries are much more clustered than would be expected by randomness. This is linked to the home market effect by Davis and Weinstein ( 2003 ). In a neoclassical model spatial variation in expenditure on a sector should be linked with less than proportional variation in production, whereas in a geography model the home market effect would cause the increase in production to be more than proportional. They find the latter effect present in many manufacturing industries.

Finally, does geography matter for income differences? Effects are expected to show up in the prices of immobile factors, and, within countries, this is apparent in variations in the price of land between rural and urban areas of different sizes. Internationally, several lines of research have looked at the impact of geography on income. The impact of natural geography is studied in a line of work following Sachs and Warner ( 2001 ), pointing to the sometimes negative impact of natural resource and fossil fuel abundance on per capita incomes. The impact of economic geography is studied by constructing various measures of access to markets and to suppliers (measures derived from estimating gravity trade models) and estimating their impact on income (Head & Mayer, 2011 ; Redding & Venables, 2004 ). These measures explain a substantial proportion of cross-country variation in per capita income, and estimated parameters are consistent with plausible values of model parameters. Establishing that the relationship is causal is problematic, particularly as other variables such as quality of institutions may be highly correlated with market access and income levels. In the search to find solutions to this problem, researchers have looked for natural experiments, one notable one being the partition of Germany (Redding & Sturm, 2008 ). West German cities close to the border with the East experienced substantial population decline, attributed by the authors to the loss of previous trading links and market access. 18

Future Directions

Geography is now incorporated in economic models of international trade, although the focus has been predominantly on trade costs and gravity rather than the richer story of firm location, unevenness, and multiple equilibria. Firm location and spatial unevenness are developed more fully in the literature on urban and regional economics where there is both analytical and empirical work studying the location of activity and quantifying the agglomeration forces that shape it.

These developments have laid the foundations for thinking about policy, but the research literature is far from having a robust set of guidelines for formulation of spatial policy. Vast resources are spent trying to promote the development of lagging regions—internationally, within countries, and within cities. Much of this is done in the hopes of achieving transformational change (i.e., encouraging positive feedback mechanisms to come into play so that an area will develop), but little is yet known about circumstances under which this is more or less likely to occur. 19 To take one example, China’s belt and road initiative is a trillion-dollar experiment in economic geography and trade; do we have the tools to think through its likely effects? Developing such tools remains the challenge, and one route is through the emerging literature on quantitative spatial economics in which economic geography models are calibrated to urban or national data (Donaldson, 2015 ; Redding & Rossi-Hansburg, 2017 ). Effects of policy will always be context specific and, given increasing returns and multiple equilibria, have an inherent uncertainty. Prediction may not be possible, but quantitative tools firmly grounded in theory and data will provide a way of illustrating scenarios of possible outcomes.

Further Reading

Accessible introductions:.

  • Krugman, P. R. (1991a). Geography and trade . Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
  • Moretti, E. (2013). The new geography of jobs . New York, NY: Mariner Books.

Textbook treatment:

  • Brakman, S. , Garretsen, H. , & van Marrewijk, C. (2001). An introduction to geographical economics . Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

Surveys that cover several aspects of the literature:

  • Donaldson, D. (2015). The gains from market integration. Annual Review of Economics , 7 , 619–647.
  • Duranton, G. , & Puga, D. (2004). Micro-foundations of urban agglomeration economies. In J. V. Henderson & J. F. Thisse (Eds.), Handbook of regional and urban economics (Vol. 4, pp. 2063–2117). Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.
  • Head, K. , & Mayer, T. (2004). The empirics of agglomeration and trade. Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics , 4 , 2609–2669.
  • Redding, S. J. , & Rossi-Hansburg, E. (2017). Quantitative spatial economics. Annual Review of Economics , 9 (1), 21–58.

Comprehensive statement of early development of the field:

  • Fujita, M. , Krugman, P. R. , & Venables, A. J. (1999). The spatial economy: Cities, regions, and international trade . Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
  • Allen, T. , & Arkolakis, C. (2014). Trade and the topography of the spatial economy. The Quarterly Journal of Economics , 129 (3), 1085–1139.
  • Anderson, J. (2011). The gravity model. The Annual Review of Economics , 3 (1), 133–160.
  • Armington, P. (1969). A theory of demand for products distinguished by place of production. International Monetary Fund Staff Papers , XVI , 159–178.
  • Baldwin, R. (2016). The great convergence; information technology and the new globalization . Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
  • Baldwin, R. E. , Forslid, R. , Martin, P. , Ottaviano, G. , & Robert-Nicoud, F. (2003). Economic geography and public policy . Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  • Behrens, K. , Lamorgese, A. R. , Ottaviano, G. , & Tabuchi, T. (2009). Beyond the home market effect: Market size and specialization in a multi-country world. Journal of International Economics , 79 (2), 259–265.
  • Cairncross, F. (1997). The death of distance: How the communications revolution will change our lives . London, U.K.: Orion Business Books.
  • Combes, P. , & Gobillon, L. (2015). Empirics of agglomeration economies. In G. Duranton , J. V. Henderson , & W. Strange (Eds.), Handbook of regional and urban economics (Vol. 5, pp. 247–348). Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.
  • Davis, D. R. , & Weinstein, D. E. (2003). Market access, economic geography and comparative advantage: An empirical test. Journal of International Economics , 59 , 1–23.
  • Disdier, A. C. , & Head, K. (2008). The puzzling persistence of the distance effect on bilateral trade. The Review of Economics and Statistics , 90 (1), 37–48.
  • Dixit, A. K. , & Stiglitz, J. E. (1977). Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. American Economic Review , 67 , 297–308.
  • Duranton, G. , & Venables, A. J. (2018). Place-based policies for development . World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 8410, CEPR Discussion Paper 12889. Washington, DC: World Bank.
  • Eaton, J. , & Kortum, S. (2002). Technology, geography and trade. Econometrica , 70 (5), 1741–1779.
  • Ellison, G. , & Glaeser, E. L. (1997). Geographic concentration in U.S. manufacturing industries: A Dartboard approach. Journal of Political Economy , 105 (5), 889–927.
  • Fujita, M. , & Thisse, J. F. (2002). The economics of agglomeration . Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
  • Grossman, G. M. , & Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2008). Trading tasks: A simple theory of offshoring. American Economic Review , 98 (5), 1978–1997.
  • Hausmann, R. , & Hidalgo, C. A. (2009). The building blocks of economic complexity. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America , 106 (26), 10570–10575.
  • Head, K. , & Mayer, T. (2011). Gravity, market potential and economic development. Journal of Economic Geography , 11 (2), 281–294.
  • Head, K. , & Mayer, T. (2014). Gravity equations: Workhorse, toolkit, and cookbook. In G. Gopinath , E. Helpman , & K. Rogoff (Eds.), Handbook of international economics (Vol. 4, pp. 131–195). Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.
  • Head, K. , Mayer, T. , & Ries, J. (2009). How remote is the offshoring threat? European Economic Review , 53 (1), 429–444.
  • Helpman, E. , & Krugman, P. (1985) . Market structure and foreign trade . Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
  • Hirschman, A. O. (1958). The strategy of economic development . New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
  • Kline, P. , & Moretti, E. (2013). Local economic development, agglomeration economies, and the big push: 100 years of evidence from the Tennessee Valley Authority. Quarterly Journal of Economics , 129 (1), 275–331.
  • Krugman, P. R. (1991b). Increasing returns and economic geography. Journal of Political Economy , 99 (3), 483–499.
  • Krugman, P. R. , Obstfeld, M. , & Melitz, M. (2015). International economics, theory and policy . New York, NY: Pearson.
  • Lendle, A. , Olarreaga, M. , Schropp, S. , & Vézina, P.-L. (2016). There goes gravity: eBay and the death of distance. Economic Journal , 126 (591), 406–441.
  • Markusen, J. R. (2002). Multinational firms and the theory of international trade . Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
  • Marshall, A. (1920). Principles of economics (8th ed.). London, U.K.: Macmillan.
  • Melitz, M. , & Redding, S. J. (2014). Heterogeneous firms and trade. In G. Gopinath , E. Helpman , & K. Rogoff (Eds.), Handbook of international economics (Vol. 4, pp. 1–54). Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.
  • Murphy, K. M. , Shleifer, A. , & Vishny, R. W. (1989). Income distribution, market size, and industrialization. Quarterly Journal of Economics , 104 , 537–564.
  • Myrdal, G. (1957). Economic theory and under-developed regions . London, U.K.: Duckworth.
  • Norman, V. , & Venables, A. J. (1995). International trade, factor mobility and trade costs. Economic Journal , 105 (433), 1488–1504.
  • Redding, S. J. , & Sturm, D. M. (2008). The costs of remoteness: Evidence from German division and reunification. American Economic Review , 98 (5), 1766–1797.
  • Redding, S. J. , & Turner, M. (2015). Transportation costs and the spatial organization of economic activity. In G. Duranton , J. V. Henderson , & W. Strange (Eds.), Handbook of urban and regional economics (pp. 1339–1398). Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.
  • Redding, S. J. , & Venables, A. J. (2004). Economic geography and international inequality. Journal of International Economics , 62 (1), 53–82.
  • Rosenthal, S. , & Strange, W. (2004). Evidence on the nature and sources of agglomeration economies. In V. Henderson & J.-F. Thisse (Eds.), Handbook of regional and urban economics (Vol. 4, pp. 2119–2171). Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.
  • Sachs, J. D. , & Warner, A. M. (2001). The curse of natural resources. European Economic Review , 45 (4), 827–838.
  • Tinbergen, J. (1962). Shaping the world economy: Suggestions for an international economic policy . New York, NY: Twentieth Century Fund.
  • Turing, A. (1952). The chemical basis of morphogenesis. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London , 237 , 37–72.
  • Venables, A. J. (1996). Equilibrium locations of vertically linked industries. International Economic Review , 37 , 341–359.

1. There are also distinct literatures on frictions due to trade policy and on the effects of factor mobility. See Norman and Venables ( 1995 ) for a synthesis of trade frictions and factor mobility in a Heckscher-Ohlin framework.

2. Trade can be generated by national-level product differentiation (Armington, 1969 ), Ricardian productivity differences in a multicommodity setting (Eaton & Kortum, 2002 ), or factor endowments with firm level product differentiation (Helpman & Krugman, 1985 ).

3. Nineteenth-century “social physics” hypothesized that human interactions were analogous to physical ones. Physical gravity operates in three-dimensional space so distance has coefficient –2. The surface of the earth is two-dimensional, so the analogous gravity coefficient would be expected to be –1.

4. The terminology follows Redding and Venables ( 2004 ). The familiar concept of country i market access is an inverse distance weighted sum of market capacities across countries j with which i trades, market access i = ∑ j m j / d i j . See also Anderson ( 2011 ) for links with the gravity model.

5. The benchmark model sketched here assumes that all firms in a particular country/industry are symmetric. If firms are heterogeneous (e.g., in their productivity levels), then the marginal firm breaks even and firms with higher productivities make positive profits. For development of such models see Melitz and Redding ( 2014 ).

6. In a particular sector of a closed economy there is just one equation and a single variable n 1 . In a multicountry context i , j are values of an index over the total number of countries so that Equation 2 is a simultaneous system determining the number of firms active in each country. The solution is subject to the impossibility of a negative number of firms, so Δ n i ≤ 0 , n i ≥ 0 , complementary slack.

7. In the Dixit-Stiglitz framework, the measure of market crowdedness is the price index of all varieties sold in the country j market.

8. For generalization of the home market effect to many countries and industries, see Behrens, Lamorgese, Ottaviano, and Tabuchi ( 2009 ).

9. Discussion dates back to at least Alfred Marshall (Marshall, 1920 ). For a modern survey, see Duranton and Puga ( 2004 ).

10. The supplier will capture the full benefit only if able to perfectly price discriminate. Otherwise, the customer will also receive some consumer/user surplus on the introduction of a new product. This observation is central to the wide range of economic models in which the number and variety of goods and services offered is endogenous (see Dixit & Stiglitz, 1977 ).

11. For an elegant synthesis of the tension between dispersion and agglomeration forces and an application to intracountry unevenness, see Allen and Arkolakis ( 2014 ).

12. This section draws on Venables ( 1996 ); see also Fujita et al. ( 1999 ).

13. In general this would be through a full input-output matrix. In this example it is aggregated to a single sector using some of its own (differentiated) outputs as inputs.

14. See Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg ( 2008 ) and, for a wider view of global production networks, Baldwin ( 2016 ).

15. See Rosenthal and Strange ( 2004 ) for a survey.

16. In some contexts, it may not be appropriate to impose all these controls. Suppose someone achieves high productivity by undertaking education to acquire a skill that is in demand only in large cities. Then both the city and the education are necessary for attaining the productivity, and it would be wrong to attribute it all to education.

17. The city of Qiaotou produces 60% of the world’s buttons and 200,000km of zippers per year.

18. There are substantial recent literatures re-evaluating the gains from trade and looking at the effects of transport improvements. These are outside the scope of this article and are both surveyed in Donaldson ( 2015 ).

19. An exception is the careful study of the Tennessee Valley Authority by Kline and Moretti ( 2013 ). See Duranton and Venables ( 2018 ) for further discussion of issues and a review of some of this literature.

Related Articles

  • Trade Agreements: Theoretical Foundations
  • Preferential Trade Agreements: Recent Theoretical and Empirical Developments
  • Globalization, Trade, and Health Economics
  • The Law and Political Economy of International Trade Agreements

Printed from Oxford Research Encyclopedias, Economics and Finance. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a single article for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).

date: 28 April 2024

  • Cookie Policy
  • Privacy Policy
  • Legal Notice
  • Accessibility
  • [66.249.64.20|185.80.151.41]
  • 185.80.151.41

Character limit 500 /500

Development, Geography, and Economic Theory

Development, Geography, and Economic Theory

Paul Krugman is Professor of Economics and International Affairs at Princeton University and a New York Times columnist. He was awarded the Nobel Prize for Economics in 2008.

Why do certain ideas gain currency in economics while others fall by the wayside? Paul Krugman argues that the unwillingness of mainstream economists to think about what they could not formalize led them to ignore ideas that turn out, in retrospect, to have been very good ones. Krugman examines the course of economic geograph and development theory to shed light on the nature of economic inquiry. He traces how development theory lost its huge initial influence and virtually disappeared from economic discourse after it became clear that many of the theory's main insights could not be clearly modeled. Economic geography seems to have fared even worse, as economists shied away from grappling with questions about space—such as the size, location, or even existence of cities—because the "terrain was seen as unsuitable for the tools at hand." Krugman's book, however, is not a call to abandon economic modeling. He concludes with a reminder of why insisting on the use of models may be right, even when these sometimes lead economists to overlook good ideas. He also recaps the discussion of development and economic geography with a commentary on recent developments in those fields and areas where further inquiry looks most promising.

  • Permissions
  • Cite Icon Cite

Development, Geography, and Economic Theory By: Paul Krugman https://doi.org/10.7551/mitpress/2389.001.0001 ISBN (electronic): 9780262277686 Publisher: The MIT Press Published: 1995

Download citation file:

  • Ris (Zotero)
  • Reference Manager

Table of Contents

  • Preface Doi: https://doi.org/10.7551/mitpress/2389.003.0001 Open the PDF Link PDF for Preface in another window
  • 1: The Fall and Rise of Development Economics Doi: https://doi.org/10.7551/mitpress/2389.003.0002 Open the PDF Link PDF for 1: The Fall and Rise of Development Economics in another window
  • 2: Geography Lost and Found Doi: https://doi.org/10.7551/mitpress/2389.003.0003 Open the PDF Link PDF for 2: Geography Lost and Found in another window
  • 3: Models and Metaphors Doi: https://doi.org/10.7551/mitpress/2389.003.0004 Open the PDF Link PDF for 3: Models and Metaphors in another window
  • Appendix Doi: https://doi.org/10.7551/mitpress/2389.003.0005 Open the PDF Link PDF for Appendix in another window
  • Notes Doi: https://doi.org/10.7551/mitpress/2389.003.0006 Open the PDF Link PDF for Notes in another window
  • References Doi: https://doi.org/10.7551/mitpress/2389.003.0007 Open the PDF Link PDF for References in another window
  • Index Doi: https://doi.org/10.7551/mitpress/2389.003.0008 Open the PDF Link PDF for Index in another window
  • Open Access

A product of The MIT Press

Mit press direct.

  • About MIT Press Direct

Information

  • Accessibility
  • For Authors
  • For Customers
  • For Librarians
  • Direct to Open
  • Media Inquiries
  • Rights and Permissions
  • For Advertisers
  • About the MIT Press
  • The MIT Press Reader
  • MIT Press Blog
  • Seasonal Catalogs
  • MIT Press Home
  • Give to the MIT Press
  • Direct Service Desk
  • Terms of Use
  • Privacy Statement
  • Crossref Member
  • COUNTER Member  
  • The MIT Press colophon is registered in the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

  • Search Menu
  • Browse content in A - General Economics and Teaching
  • Browse content in A1 - General Economics
  • A12 - Relation of Economics to Other Disciplines
  • A13 - Relation of Economics to Social Values
  • A14 - Sociology of Economics
  • Browse content in B - History of Economic Thought, Methodology, and Heterodox Approaches
  • Browse content in B2 - History of Economic Thought since 1925
  • B25 - Historical; Institutional; Evolutionary; Austrian
  • B26 - Financial Economics
  • Browse content in B4 - Economic Methodology
  • B40 - General
  • B41 - Economic Methodology
  • Browse content in B5 - Current Heterodox Approaches
  • B52 - Institutional; Evolutionary
  • Browse content in C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods
  • Browse content in C0 - General
  • C01 - Econometrics
  • Browse content in C1 - Econometric and Statistical Methods and Methodology: General
  • C11 - Bayesian Analysis: General
  • C12 - Hypothesis Testing: General
  • C14 - Semiparametric and Nonparametric Methods: General
  • C15 - Statistical Simulation Methods: General
  • Browse content in C2 - Single Equation Models; Single Variables
  • C21 - Cross-Sectional Models; Spatial Models; Treatment Effect Models; Quantile Regressions
  • C23 - Panel Data Models; Spatio-temporal Models
  • C25 - Discrete Regression and Qualitative Choice Models; Discrete Regressors; Proportions; Probabilities
  • C26 - Instrumental Variables (IV) Estimation
  • Browse content in C3 - Multiple or Simultaneous Equation Models; Multiple Variables
  • C31 - Cross-Sectional Models; Spatial Models; Treatment Effect Models; Quantile Regressions; Social Interaction Models
  • C33 - Panel Data Models; Spatio-temporal Models
  • C38 - Classification Methods; Cluster Analysis; Principal Components; Factor Models
  • Browse content in C4 - Econometric and Statistical Methods: Special Topics
  • C40 - General
  • C41 - Duration Analysis; Optimal Timing Strategies
  • C49 - Other
  • Browse content in C6 - Mathematical Methods; Programming Models; Mathematical and Simulation Modeling
  • C60 - General
  • C61 - Optimization Techniques; Programming Models; Dynamic Analysis
  • C62 - Existence and Stability Conditions of Equilibrium
  • Browse content in C9 - Design of Experiments
  • C90 - General
  • C99 - Other
  • Browse content in D - Microeconomics
  • Browse content in D0 - General
  • D00 - General
  • D01 - Microeconomic Behavior: Underlying Principles
  • D02 - Institutions: Design, Formation, Operations, and Impact
  • D03 - Behavioral Microeconomics: Underlying Principles
  • Browse content in D1 - Household Behavior and Family Economics
  • D13 - Household Production and Intrahousehold Allocation
  • D14 - Household Saving; Personal Finance
  • D19 - Other
  • Browse content in D2 - Production and Organizations
  • D21 - Firm Behavior: Theory
  • D22 - Firm Behavior: Empirical Analysis
  • D23 - Organizational Behavior; Transaction Costs; Property Rights
  • D24 - Production; Cost; Capital; Capital, Total Factor, and Multifactor Productivity; Capacity
  • Browse content in D3 - Distribution
  • D31 - Personal Income, Wealth, and Their Distributions
  • Browse content in D4 - Market Structure, Pricing, and Design
  • D41 - Perfect Competition
  • D43 - Oligopoly and Other Forms of Market Imperfection
  • Browse content in D5 - General Equilibrium and Disequilibrium
  • D53 - Financial Markets
  • Browse content in D6 - Welfare Economics
  • D61 - Allocative Efficiency; Cost-Benefit Analysis
  • D62 - Externalities
  • D63 - Equity, Justice, Inequality, and Other Normative Criteria and Measurement
  • D64 - Altruism; Philanthropy
  • Browse content in D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making
  • D72 - Political Processes: Rent-seeking, Lobbying, Elections, Legislatures, and Voting Behavior
  • D74 - Conflict; Conflict Resolution; Alliances; Revolutions
  • D78 - Positive Analysis of Policy Formulation and Implementation
  • Browse content in D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty
  • D80 - General
  • D81 - Criteria for Decision-Making under Risk and Uncertainty
  • D82 - Asymmetric and Private Information; Mechanism Design
  • D83 - Search; Learning; Information and Knowledge; Communication; Belief; Unawareness
  • D85 - Network Formation and Analysis: Theory
  • Browse content in D9 - Micro-Based Behavioral Economics
  • D92 - Intertemporal Firm Choice, Investment, Capacity, and Financing
  • Browse content in E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics
  • Browse content in E2 - Consumption, Saving, Production, Investment, Labor Markets, and Informal Economy
  • E21 - Consumption; Saving; Wealth
  • E22 - Investment; Capital; Intangible Capital; Capacity
  • E24 - Employment; Unemployment; Wages; Intergenerational Income Distribution; Aggregate Human Capital; Aggregate Labor Productivity
  • Browse content in E3 - Prices, Business Fluctuations, and Cycles
  • E32 - Business Fluctuations; Cycles
  • Browse content in E4 - Money and Interest Rates
  • E40 - General
  • Browse content in E5 - Monetary Policy, Central Banking, and the Supply of Money and Credit
  • E58 - Central Banks and Their Policies
  • Browse content in F - International Economics
  • Browse content in F0 - General
  • F00 - General
  • F02 - International Economic Order and Integration
  • Browse content in F1 - Trade
  • F10 - General
  • F11 - Neoclassical Models of Trade
  • F12 - Models of Trade with Imperfect Competition and Scale Economies; Fragmentation
  • F13 - Trade Policy; International Trade Organizations
  • F14 - Empirical Studies of Trade
  • F15 - Economic Integration
  • F16 - Trade and Labor Market Interactions
  • F18 - Trade and Environment
  • Browse content in F2 - International Factor Movements and International Business
  • F20 - General
  • F21 - International Investment; Long-Term Capital Movements
  • F22 - International Migration
  • F23 - Multinational Firms; International Business
  • Browse content in F3 - International Finance
  • F30 - General
  • F31 - Foreign Exchange
  • F32 - Current Account Adjustment; Short-Term Capital Movements
  • F33 - International Monetary Arrangements and Institutions
  • F34 - International Lending and Debt Problems
  • F36 - Financial Aspects of Economic Integration
  • Browse content in F4 - Macroeconomic Aspects of International Trade and Finance
  • F40 - General
  • F41 - Open Economy Macroeconomics
  • F43 - Economic Growth of Open Economies
  • F44 - International Business Cycles
  • Browse content in F5 - International Relations, National Security, and International Political Economy
  • F50 - General
  • F52 - National Security; Economic Nationalism
  • F55 - International Institutional Arrangements
  • Browse content in F6 - Economic Impacts of Globalization
  • F60 - General
  • F61 - Microeconomic Impacts
  • F63 - Economic Development
  • F65 - Finance
  • F66 - Labor
  • F68 - Policy
  • Browse content in G - Financial Economics
  • Browse content in G0 - General
  • G00 - General
  • G01 - Financial Crises
  • G02 - Behavioral Finance: Underlying Principles
  • Browse content in G1 - General Financial Markets
  • G10 - General
  • G11 - Portfolio Choice; Investment Decisions
  • G12 - Asset Pricing; Trading volume; Bond Interest Rates
  • G14 - Information and Market Efficiency; Event Studies; Insider Trading
  • G15 - International Financial Markets
  • G18 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • Browse content in G2 - Financial Institutions and Services
  • G20 - General
  • G21 - Banks; Depository Institutions; Micro Finance Institutions; Mortgages
  • G22 - Insurance; Insurance Companies; Actuarial Studies
  • G23 - Non-bank Financial Institutions; Financial Instruments; Institutional Investors
  • G24 - Investment Banking; Venture Capital; Brokerage; Ratings and Ratings Agencies
  • G28 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • Browse content in G3 - Corporate Finance and Governance
  • G30 - General
  • G31 - Capital Budgeting; Fixed Investment and Inventory Studies; Capacity
  • G32 - Financing Policy; Financial Risk and Risk Management; Capital and Ownership Structure; Value of Firms; Goodwill
  • G34 - Mergers; Acquisitions; Restructuring; Corporate Governance
  • G38 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • Browse content in H - Public Economics
  • H0 - General
  • Browse content in H1 - Structure and Scope of Government
  • H11 - Structure, Scope, and Performance of Government
  • H13 - Economics of Eminent Domain; Expropriation; Nationalization
  • Browse content in H2 - Taxation, Subsidies, and Revenue
  • H20 - General
  • H21 - Efficiency; Optimal Taxation
  • H23 - Externalities; Redistributive Effects; Environmental Taxes and Subsidies
  • H25 - Business Taxes and Subsidies
  • H26 - Tax Evasion and Avoidance
  • H27 - Other Sources of Revenue
  • Browse content in H3 - Fiscal Policies and Behavior of Economic Agents
  • H31 - Household
  • Browse content in H4 - Publicly Provided Goods
  • H41 - Public Goods
  • H43 - Project Evaluation; Social Discount Rate
  • H44 - Publicly Provided Goods: Mixed Markets
  • Browse content in H5 - National Government Expenditures and Related Policies
  • H52 - Government Expenditures and Education
  • H53 - Government Expenditures and Welfare Programs
  • H54 - Infrastructures; Other Public Investment and Capital Stock
  • H55 - Social Security and Public Pensions
  • H56 - National Security and War
  • H57 - Procurement
  • Browse content in H7 - State and Local Government; Intergovernmental Relations
  • H70 - General
  • H71 - State and Local Taxation, Subsidies, and Revenue
  • H72 - State and Local Budget and Expenditures
  • H73 - Interjurisdictional Differentials and Their Effects
  • H74 - State and Local Borrowing
  • H75 - State and Local Government: Health; Education; Welfare; Public Pensions
  • H76 - State and Local Government: Other Expenditure Categories
  • H77 - Intergovernmental Relations; Federalism; Secession
  • Browse content in H8 - Miscellaneous Issues
  • H81 - Governmental Loans; Loan Guarantees; Credits; Grants; Bailouts
  • H89 - Other
  • Browse content in I - Health, Education, and Welfare
  • I0 - General
  • Browse content in I1 - Health
  • I14 - Health and Inequality
  • I18 - Government Policy; Regulation; Public Health
  • Browse content in I2 - Education and Research Institutions
  • I20 - General
  • I21 - Analysis of Education
  • I22 - Educational Finance; Financial Aid
  • I23 - Higher Education; Research Institutions
  • I24 - Education and Inequality
  • I25 - Education and Economic Development
  • I28 - Government Policy
  • I29 - Other
  • Browse content in I3 - Welfare, Well-Being, and Poverty
  • I30 - General
  • I31 - General Welfare
  • I32 - Measurement and Analysis of Poverty
  • I38 - Government Policy; Provision and Effects of Welfare Programs
  • Browse content in J - Labor and Demographic Economics
  • Browse content in J0 - General
  • J01 - Labor Economics: General
  • Browse content in J1 - Demographic Economics
  • J10 - General
  • J11 - Demographic Trends, Macroeconomic Effects, and Forecasts
  • J12 - Marriage; Marital Dissolution; Family Structure; Domestic Abuse
  • J13 - Fertility; Family Planning; Child Care; Children; Youth
  • J15 - Economics of Minorities, Races, Indigenous Peoples, and Immigrants; Non-labor Discrimination
  • J16 - Economics of Gender; Non-labor Discrimination
  • J18 - Public Policy
  • J19 - Other
  • Browse content in J2 - Demand and Supply of Labor
  • J21 - Labor Force and Employment, Size, and Structure
  • J22 - Time Allocation and Labor Supply
  • J23 - Labor Demand
  • J24 - Human Capital; Skills; Occupational Choice; Labor Productivity
  • Browse content in J3 - Wages, Compensation, and Labor Costs
  • J30 - General
  • J31 - Wage Level and Structure; Wage Differentials
  • J32 - Nonwage Labor Costs and Benefits; Retirement Plans; Private Pensions
  • J38 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in J4 - Particular Labor Markets
  • J40 - General
  • J41 - Labor Contracts
  • J42 - Monopsony; Segmented Labor Markets
  • J44 - Professional Labor Markets; Occupational Licensing
  • J45 - Public Sector Labor Markets
  • Browse content in J5 - Labor-Management Relations, Trade Unions, and Collective Bargaining
  • J50 - General
  • J51 - Trade Unions: Objectives, Structure, and Effects
  • J53 - Labor-Management Relations; Industrial Jurisprudence
  • Browse content in J6 - Mobility, Unemployment, Vacancies, and Immigrant Workers
  • J60 - General
  • J61 - Geographic Labor Mobility; Immigrant Workers
  • J62 - Job, Occupational, and Intergenerational Mobility
  • J63 - Turnover; Vacancies; Layoffs
  • J64 - Unemployment: Models, Duration, Incidence, and Job Search
  • J65 - Unemployment Insurance; Severance Pay; Plant Closings
  • Browse content in J7 - Labor Discrimination
  • J71 - Discrimination
  • Browse content in J8 - Labor Standards: National and International
  • J80 - General
  • J81 - Working Conditions
  • J83 - Workers' Rights
  • Browse content in K - Law and Economics
  • Browse content in K0 - General
  • K00 - General
  • Browse content in K2 - Regulation and Business Law
  • K23 - Regulated Industries and Administrative Law
  • Browse content in K3 - Other Substantive Areas of Law
  • K35 - Personal Bankruptcy Law
  • K37 - Immigration Law
  • Browse content in K4 - Legal Procedure, the Legal System, and Illegal Behavior
  • K41 - Litigation Process
  • K42 - Illegal Behavior and the Enforcement of Law
  • K49 - Other
  • Browse content in L - Industrial Organization
  • Browse content in L0 - General
  • L00 - General
  • Browse content in L1 - Market Structure, Firm Strategy, and Market Performance
  • L10 - General
  • L11 - Production, Pricing, and Market Structure; Size Distribution of Firms
  • L13 - Oligopoly and Other Imperfect Markets
  • L14 - Transactional Relationships; Contracts and Reputation; Networks
  • L16 - Industrial Organization and Macroeconomics: Industrial Structure and Structural Change; Industrial Price Indices
  • Browse content in L2 - Firm Objectives, Organization, and Behavior
  • L20 - General
  • L21 - Business Objectives of the Firm
  • L22 - Firm Organization and Market Structure
  • L23 - Organization of Production
  • L25 - Firm Performance: Size, Diversification, and Scope
  • L26 - Entrepreneurship
  • Browse content in L3 - Nonprofit Organizations and Public Enterprise
  • L30 - General
  • L31 - Nonprofit Institutions; NGOs; Social Entrepreneurship
  • L38 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in L5 - Regulation and Industrial Policy
  • L51 - Economics of Regulation
  • L52 - Industrial Policy; Sectoral Planning Methods
  • L53 - Enterprise Policy
  • Browse content in L6 - Industry Studies: Manufacturing
  • L60 - General
  • L62 - Automobiles; Other Transportation Equipment; Related Parts and Equipment
  • L63 - Microelectronics; Computers; Communications Equipment
  • L64 - Other Machinery; Business Equipment; Armaments
  • L65 - Chemicals; Rubber; Drugs; Biotechnology
  • L66 - Food; Beverages; Cosmetics; Tobacco; Wine and Spirits
  • L67 - Other Consumer Nondurables: Clothing, Textiles, Shoes, and Leather Goods; Household Goods; Sports Equipment
  • Browse content in L7 - Industry Studies: Primary Products and Construction
  • L71 - Mining, Extraction, and Refining: Hydrocarbon Fuels
  • L74 - Construction
  • Browse content in L8 - Industry Studies: Services
  • L80 - General
  • L81 - Retail and Wholesale Trade; e-Commerce
  • L82 - Entertainment; Media
  • L83 - Sports; Gambling; Recreation; Tourism
  • L84 - Personal, Professional, and Business Services
  • L85 - Real Estate Services
  • L86 - Information and Internet Services; Computer Software
  • Browse content in L9 - Industry Studies: Transportation and Utilities
  • L90 - General
  • L91 - Transportation: General
  • L92 - Railroads and Other Surface Transportation
  • L93 - Air Transportation
  • Browse content in M - Business Administration and Business Economics; Marketing; Accounting; Personnel Economics
  • Browse content in M1 - Business Administration
  • M10 - General
  • M13 - New Firms; Startups
  • M16 - International Business Administration
  • Browse content in M2 - Business Economics
  • M21 - Business Economics
  • Browse content in M3 - Marketing and Advertising
  • M30 - General
  • M31 - Marketing
  • M39 - Other
  • Browse content in M5 - Personnel Economics
  • M51 - Firm Employment Decisions; Promotions
  • M52 - Compensation and Compensation Methods and Their Effects
  • Browse content in N - Economic History
  • Browse content in N1 - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics; Industrial Structure; Growth; Fluctuations
  • N10 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N13 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • N16 - Latin America; Caribbean
  • Browse content in N2 - Financial Markets and Institutions
  • N20 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N25 - Asia including Middle East
  • Browse content in N3 - Labor and Consumers, Demography, Education, Health, Welfare, Income, Wealth, Religion, and Philanthropy
  • N30 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N33 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • N34 - Europe: 1913-
  • N37 - Africa; Oceania
  • Browse content in N4 - Government, War, Law, International Relations, and Regulation
  • N44 - Europe: 1913-
  • Browse content in N5 - Agriculture, Natural Resources, Environment, and Extractive Industries
  • N50 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N51 - U.S.; Canada: Pre-1913
  • N57 - Africa; Oceania
  • Browse content in N6 - Manufacturing and Construction
  • N61 - U.S.; Canada: Pre-1913
  • N64 - Europe: 1913-
  • Browse content in N7 - Transport, Trade, Energy, Technology, and Other Services
  • N70 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N71 - U.S.; Canada: Pre-1913
  • N72 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • N73 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • N74 - Europe: 1913-
  • N77 - Africa; Oceania
  • Browse content in N9 - Regional and Urban History
  • N90 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N92 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • N93 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • N94 - Europe: 1913-
  • N95 - Asia including Middle East
  • N97 - Africa; Oceania
  • Browse content in O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth
  • Browse content in O1 - Economic Development
  • O10 - General
  • O11 - Macroeconomic Analyses of Economic Development
  • O12 - Microeconomic Analyses of Economic Development
  • O13 - Agriculture; Natural Resources; Energy; Environment; Other Primary Products
  • O14 - Industrialization; Manufacturing and Service Industries; Choice of Technology
  • O15 - Human Resources; Human Development; Income Distribution; Migration
  • O16 - Financial Markets; Saving and Capital Investment; Corporate Finance and Governance
  • O17 - Formal and Informal Sectors; Shadow Economy; Institutional Arrangements
  • O18 - Urban, Rural, Regional, and Transportation Analysis; Housing; Infrastructure
  • O19 - International Linkages to Development; Role of International Organizations
  • Browse content in O2 - Development Planning and Policy
  • O20 - General
  • O21 - Planning Models; Planning Policy
  • O24 - Trade Policy; Factor Movement Policy; Foreign Exchange Policy
  • O25 - Industrial Policy
  • Browse content in O3 - Innovation; Research and Development; Technological Change; Intellectual Property Rights
  • O30 - General
  • O31 - Innovation and Invention: Processes and Incentives
  • O32 - Management of Technological Innovation and R&D
  • O33 - Technological Change: Choices and Consequences; Diffusion Processes
  • O34 - Intellectual Property and Intellectual Capital
  • O38 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in O4 - Economic Growth and Aggregate Productivity
  • O40 - General
  • O41 - One, Two, and Multisector Growth Models
  • O43 - Institutions and Growth
  • O47 - Empirical Studies of Economic Growth; Aggregate Productivity; Cross-Country Output Convergence
  • Browse content in O5 - Economywide Country Studies
  • O51 - U.S.; Canada
  • O52 - Europe
  • O53 - Asia including Middle East
  • O54 - Latin America; Caribbean
  • O55 - Africa
  • O57 - Comparative Studies of Countries
  • Browse content in P - Economic Systems
  • Browse content in P1 - Capitalist Systems
  • P12 - Capitalist Enterprises
  • P13 - Cooperative Enterprises
  • P16 - Political Economy
  • P18 - Energy: Environment
  • Browse content in P2 - Socialist Systems and Transitional Economies
  • P20 - General
  • P25 - Urban, Rural, and Regional Economics
  • P26 - Political Economy; Property Rights
  • Browse content in P3 - Socialist Institutions and Their Transitions
  • P30 - General
  • P31 - Socialist Enterprises and Their Transitions
  • Browse content in P4 - Other Economic Systems
  • P48 - Political Economy; Legal Institutions; Property Rights; Natural Resources; Energy; Environment; Regional Studies
  • Browse content in P5 - Comparative Economic Systems
  • P51 - Comparative Analysis of Economic Systems
  • Browse content in Q - Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics; Environmental and Ecological Economics
  • Browse content in Q0 - General
  • Q00 - General
  • Q01 - Sustainable Development
  • Q02 - Commodity Markets
  • Browse content in Q1 - Agriculture
  • Q10 - General
  • Q12 - Micro Analysis of Farm Firms, Farm Households, and Farm Input Markets
  • Q15 - Land Ownership and Tenure; Land Reform; Land Use; Irrigation; Agriculture and Environment
  • Q16 - R&D; Agricultural Technology; Biofuels; Agricultural Extension Services
  • Q17 - Agriculture in International Trade
  • Browse content in Q2 - Renewable Resources and Conservation
  • Q20 - General
  • Q28 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in Q3 - Nonrenewable Resources and Conservation
  • Q32 - Exhaustible Resources and Economic Development
  • Q34 - Natural Resources and Domestic and International Conflicts
  • Q38 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in Q4 - Energy
  • Q40 - General
  • Q42 - Alternative Energy Sources
  • Q48 - Government Policy
  • Q49 - Other
  • Browse content in Q5 - Environmental Economics
  • Q50 - General
  • Q51 - Valuation of Environmental Effects
  • Q52 - Pollution Control Adoption Costs; Distributional Effects; Employment Effects
  • Q53 - Air Pollution; Water Pollution; Noise; Hazardous Waste; Solid Waste; Recycling
  • Q54 - Climate; Natural Disasters; Global Warming
  • Q55 - Technological Innovation
  • Q56 - Environment and Development; Environment and Trade; Sustainability; Environmental Accounts and Accounting; Environmental Equity; Population Growth
  • Browse content in R - Urban, Rural, Regional, Real Estate, and Transportation Economics
  • Browse content in R0 - General
  • R00 - General
  • Browse content in R1 - General Regional Economics
  • R10 - General
  • R11 - Regional Economic Activity: Growth, Development, Environmental Issues, and Changes
  • R12 - Size and Spatial Distributions of Regional Economic Activity
  • R13 - General Equilibrium and Welfare Economic Analysis of Regional Economies
  • R14 - Land Use Patterns
  • R15 - Econometric and Input-Output Models; Other Models
  • R19 - Other
  • Browse content in R2 - Household Analysis
  • R20 - General
  • R21 - Housing Demand
  • R23 - Regional Migration; Regional Labor Markets; Population; Neighborhood Characteristics
  • R28 - Government Policy
  • R29 - Other
  • Browse content in R3 - Real Estate Markets, Spatial Production Analysis, and Firm Location
  • R30 - General
  • R31 - Housing Supply and Markets
  • R32 - Other Spatial Production and Pricing Analysis
  • R33 - Nonagricultural and Nonresidential Real Estate Markets
  • R34 - Input Demand Analysis
  • R38 - Government Policy
  • R39 - Other
  • Browse content in R4 - Transportation Economics
  • R40 - General
  • R41 - Transportation: Demand, Supply, and Congestion; Travel Time; Safety and Accidents; Transportation Noise
  • R42 - Government and Private Investment Analysis; Road Maintenance; Transportation Planning
  • R48 - Government Pricing and Policy
  • R49 - Other
  • Browse content in R5 - Regional Government Analysis
  • R50 - General
  • R51 - Finance in Urban and Rural Economies
  • R52 - Land Use and Other Regulations
  • R53 - Public Facility Location Analysis; Public Investment and Capital Stock
  • R58 - Regional Development Planning and Policy
  • R59 - Other
  • Browse content in Y - Miscellaneous Categories
  • Browse content in Y8 - Related Disciplines
  • Y80 - Related Disciplines
  • Browse content in Z - Other Special Topics
  • Browse content in Z1 - Cultural Economics; Economic Sociology; Economic Anthropology
  • Z10 - General
  • Z11 - Economics of the Arts and Literature
  • Z12 - Religion
  • Z13 - Economic Sociology; Economic Anthropology; Social and Economic Stratification
  • Z19 - Other
  • Advance articles
  • Author Guidelines
  • Submission Site
  • Open Access
  • Why Publish
  • About Journal of Economic Geography
  • Editorial Board
  • Advertising and Corporate Services
  • Journals Career Network
  • Self-Archiving Policy
  • Dispatch Dates
  • Terms and Conditions
  • Journals on Oxford Academic
  • Books on Oxford Academic

Issue Cover

Jorge De la Roca

Stephen Gibbons 

Simona Iammarino

Amanda Ross

James Faulconbridge

About the journal

Steered by a team of editors drawn from both Geography and Economics, Journal of Economic Geography publishes original academic research and discussion of the highest scholarly standard in the field of 'economic geography' broadly defined.

Call For Papers

Explore the current open calls for papers from the Journal of Economic Geography and submit your paper.

Find out more

Special Issues Guidelines

The Journal of Economic Geography welcomes Special Issue Proposals that fit with the interdisciplinary journal’s aims and scope and significantly contribute to current debates and research in economic geography, with particular attention to diverse and inclusive teams of contributors.

Special Issue: Immigration in OECD Countries

Read the latest Special Issue, ‘Immigration in OECD Countries’. This issue brings together a range of articles reflecting on the state of immigration economics research.  

Special Issue: Economic Geography of Climate Change

Browse this Special Issue on ‘Economic Geography of Climate Change’. This issue provides foundations to well-informed policy making by addressing two main themes of the economic geography of climate change. It also considers alternative margins of adjustment, such as fertility, specialization and trade.

Latest articles

Prize winners, urban land institute prize winner 2018.

The Urban Land Institute Prize is awarded annually to the author(s) of the best JOEG paper published online in the previous calendar year.

The 2018 prize has been awarded to Yong Suk Lee, for his paper, "Entrepreneurship, small businesses and economic growth in cities".

Find out more about the prize

Best Referee Award

The JOEG Best Referee Award is given annually to the referees used in the previous year who, in the views of the Editors, have made an outstanding contribution to Journal of Economic Geography in terms of the number of reviews provided, speed of response, and quality and helpfulness of the comments.

JEL Codes Explained

Articles from Oxford Journals economics titles are classified according to the system used by the Journal of Economic Literature (commonly known as 'JEL codes').

New option for authors to share reports from previous submissions

JoEG authors who have previously submitted their article to a select list of journals now have the option to share the decision letter(s) and reviews with the JoEG editors.

Recommend to your library

Recommend to your library

Fill out our simple online form to recommend Journal of Economic Geography to your library.

Recommend now

COPE logo

Committee on Publication Ethics (COPE)

This journal is a member of and subscribes to the principles of the Committee on Publication Ethics (COPE)

publicationethics.org

Related Titles

Cover image of current issue from Socio-Economic Review

  • Recommend to your Library

Affiliations

  • Online ISSN 1468-2710
  • Print ISSN 1468-2702
  • Copyright © 2024 Oxford University Press
  • About Oxford Academic
  • Publish journals with us
  • University press partners
  • What we publish
  • New features  
  • Open access
  • Institutional account management
  • Rights and permissions
  • Get help with access
  • Accessibility
  • Advertising
  • Media enquiries
  • Oxford University Press
  • Oxford Languages
  • University of Oxford

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University's objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide

  • Copyright © 2024 Oxford University Press
  • Cookie settings
  • Cookie policy
  • Privacy policy
  • Legal notice

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

This PDF is available to Subscribers Only

For full access to this pdf, sign in to an existing account, or purchase an annual subscription.

MIT Press

On the site

Ohlin lectures.

  • business & economics

Development, Geography, and Economic Theory

Development, Geography, and Economic Theory

by Paul Krugman

ISBN: 9780262611350

Pub date: August 21, 1997

  • Publisher: The MIT Press

127 pp. , 5 x 8 in ,

ISBN: 9780262112031

Pub date: September 15, 1995

  • 9780262611350
  • Published: August 1997
  • 9780262112031
  • Published: September 1995
  • MIT Press Bookstore
  • Penguin Random House
  • Barnes and Noble
  • Bookshop.org
  • Books a Million

Other Retailers:

  • Amazon.co.uk
  • Waterstones
  • Description

Why do certain ideas gain currency in economics while others fall by the wayside? Paul Krugman argues that the unwillingness of mainstream economists to think about what they could not formalize led them to ignore ideas that turn out, in retrospect, to have been very good ones. Krugman examines the course of economic geograph and development theory to shed light on the nature of economic inquiry. He traces how development theory lost its huge initial influence and virtually disappeared from economic discourse after it became clear that many of the theory's main insights could not be clearly modeled. Economic geography seems to have fared even worse, as economists shied away from grappling with questions about space—such as the size, location, or even existence of cities—because the "terrain was seen as unsuitable for the tools at hand." Krugman's book, however, is not a call to abandon economic modeling. He concludes with a reminder of why insisting on the use of models may be right, even when these sometimes lead economists to overlook good ideas. He also recaps the discussion of development and economic geography with a commentary on recent developments in those fields and areas where further inquiry looks most promising.

Paul Krugman is Professor of Economics and International Affairs at Princeton University and a New York Times columnist. He was awarded the Nobel Prize for Economics in 2008.

A stimulating essay by one of the world's most thoughtful and innovative economists. Paul Ormerod The Times Higher Education Supplement
This is a book that should be read by all economists. Roger E. Backhouse The Economic Journal

Related Books

Investors and Exploiters in Ecology and Economics

Human Geography

  • Defining human geography
  • Cultural geography
  • Economic geography
  • Feminist geography
  • Migration and detention
  • Statelessness
  • Feminist political geography
  • Geopolitics
  • Population studies
  • Travel and tourism
  • Gentrification
  • Scholarly communication This link opens in a new window

Subject Librarian

Profile Photo

Other library resource(s)

Film art

Keeping up with the journal literature

geography hypothesis economics

You can get the app from the App Store or Google Play.

Don't own or use a mobile device? You can still use BrowZine! It's now available in a web version. You can get to it here . The web version works the same way as the app version. Find the journals you like, create a custom Bookshelf, get ToCs and read the articles you want.

A short definition for Economic geography

A subdiscipline of geography that seeks to describe and explain the absolute and relative location of economic activities, and the flows of information, raw materials, goods, and people that connect otherwise separate local, regional, and national economies. It originated in the late 19th century but, unlike its academic cousin, economics, did not initially favour theory . In the form of commercial geography , it tended to be highly empirical , attending to the relations between a location’s natural and human resource base and the character of its economy. The geography of the production of specific commodities was thus based on observation, not deductions from first economic principles. However, this changed from the mid-1950s. Economic geography was, along with urban geography , at the leading edge of the Quantitative and Scientific Revolution in Anglophone human geography. Partly inspired by the earlier research of Alfred Weber and Walter Christaller , a new generation of economic geographers began to look for consistent patterns in the economic landscape that could be explained with reference to producers acting rationally on the basis of their existing resources, the location of their markets, the transportation costs of moving inputs and finished goods, and so on. Location theory in various forms became a major preoccupation, with economic geographers gathering and analysing quantitative data about all manner of commodity producers in order to identity spatial regularities and departures therefrom. There was an emphasis on describing and seeking to explain spatial decision-making by firms, commuters, labour migrants, and so on. This approach bled into what was called ‘*regional science’, which was linked to government planning and problem-solving.
However, from the early 1970s a new generation of economic geographers began to question quantitative economic geography. As part of the radical geography movement inspired by the worldwide political protests of 1968, these geographers offered four criticisms of the research pursued by an older generation. First, it was accused of a naive objectivism, or belief that the ‘facts’ could provide a value-free, unbiased test of a theory. Second, it was criticized for its theoretical assumptions, notably the assumption that economic actors are governed by a universal form of reason ( homo economicus ). Third, it was accused of focusing on phenomenal forms not underlying economic processes. Fourth, it was criticized for treating the world’s economic geography as if it should (or would) display a spatial order, such that place and regional differences were mere ‘noise’ to be filtered out in the search for general patterns.
Out of these criticisms emerged a new kind of economic geography indebted to political economy , especially Marxism . This research focused on how economic actors had their spatial decision-making structured by the logics of capitalism , a historically specific system that created its own signature geographies. According to David Harvey in The Limits to Capital (1982), capitalism rests on a geographical tension between fixity and motion, concentration and dispersal, producing inter-place competition and the compulsion for firms and investors to seek out new opportunities in other regions. Like his spatial science predecessors, Harvey believed economic activity had a certain spatial order to it, but unlike them, saw this order as fluid and unstable.
Political economic geographers like Harvey saw spatial decision-making by economic actors as structured by definite ‘rules’ and pressures specific to capitalism, and they also saw economic decision-making as not purely ‘rational’, but the result of a combination of imperfect reasoning, guess work, and other distinctively human characteristics. They also focused on large firms in order to highlight their considerable importance for jobs, income, taxation, and wider local and national economies. Doreen Massey’s Spatial Divisions of Labour (1984) and Peter Dicken’s Global Shift (1986) were two important contributions here during the 1980s. Dicken’s book was among several works that analysed the decline of old industrial regions in North America and Europe and the rise of ‘newly industrializing economies’ in the Far East and elsewhere. Much of this work was inspired by the neo-Marxist Regulation Theory of political economy. Aside from examining firm behaviour within a wider capitalist context, there were also important early attempts to understand the geographical concentrations and flows of money , notably loans by Western banks to developing countries that ended with a debt crisis by the mid-1980s. Stuart Corbridge ’s Debt and Development (1993) is an exemplar of this work. Still other political economic research analysed the connections between national states and economic activity, with a particular focus on the attempt of hegemonic countries to maintain their relative economic prowess. John Agnew and Stuart Corbridge ’s Mastering Space (1995) is an exemplar of this attempt to link economic and political geography together. Agnew has gone on to explore the economic underpinnings of America’s waning political hegemony (in Hegemony 2005).
Much of this research was theoretically innovative and sophisticated, but it tended to avoid quantitative approaches, favouring more qualitative ones. One justification for this was that it is important to understand how and why economic actors do what they do on their own terms. However, quantitative approaches to describing and explaining the changing patterns of economic growth remain important, with certain university geography departments making this a signature of their research (such as the London School of Economics). In California, Michael Storper and Allen Scott have used secondary quantitative data sets in their explorations of the roots of sustained regional economic growth. These approaches rarely extend to forecasting economic geographies, remaining focused on current and past patterns of investment and production. Economic geography’s relation to mainstream economics has grown closer since the creation of the Journal of Economic Geography in 2000. However, the subdiscipline is far more politically left-wing than fifty years ago and today it draws much intellectual inspiration from the critical wings of economic sociology, business studies, the sociology of work, and management studies. The effects of the 1970s critique of location theory endure. Leading economic geographers have been critics of neoliberalism and have analysed capitalism from the perspective of ordinary working people ( see labour geography ), in the process highlighting the key links between production and social reproduction . Many have also explored how economic geographies are implicated in culture in various complex ways, thus challenging economists’ belief that ‘the economy’ is something separate in kind. In sum, economic geography today is plural and dominated by no one approach. This makes it a rich environment for practitioners but threatens to weaken the field’s external visibility and impact in academia and the wider society.

Rogers, A., Castree, N., & Kitchin, R. (2013). " Economic geography ." In  A Dictionary of Human Geography . Oxford University Press. Retrieved 24 Jan. 2022 

In the Library's collection

Economic geography can be found in different areas of the library's collections. The main 2 areas include the call number range HF 1021 through HF 1027 (general information) and HC 94 through HC 1085.2 (specific countries and regions). These ranges can be found on Berry Level 3 .

  • economic geography
  • international economic integration
  • commercial geography

Introductory reading(s)

Cover art

Selected book titles

Cover art

Finding journal titles & articles

Articles and other writings about economic geography can be found in many publications. Our collection includes several journals which look exclusively at economic geography. Below is a short list of economic geography journals. Or you can begin your research using the search box at the top of the page.

Issue cover art

Internet resource(s)

Sourcemap logo

  • << Previous: Cultural geography
  • Next: Feminist geography >>
  • Last Updated: Apr 12, 2024 10:28 AM
  • URL: https://researchguides.dartmouth.edu/human_geography

The Real Economy

  • Jonathan Levy

Before you purchase audiobooks and ebooks

Please note that audiobooks and ebooks purchased from this site must be accessed on the Princeton University Press app. After you make your purchase, you will receive an email with instructions on how to download the app. Learn more about audio and ebooks .

Support your local independent bookstore.

  • United States
  • United Kingdom

Economics & Finance

The Real Economy: History and Theory

A provocative new theory of “the economy,” its history, and its politics that better unites history and economics

geography hypothesis economics

  • Download Cover

What is the economy, really? Is it a “market sector,” a “general equilibrium,” the “gross domestic product”? Economics today has become so preoccupied with methods that economists risk losing sight of the economy itself. Meanwhile, other disciplines, although often intent on criticizing the methods of economics, have failed to articulate an alternative vision of the economy. Before the ascent of postwar neoclassical economics, fierce debates raged, as many different visions of the economy circulated and competed with one another. In The Real Economy , Jonathan Levy returns to the spirit of this earlier era, which, in all its contentiousness, gave birth to the discipline of economics. Drawing inspiration particularly from Thorstein Veblen and John Maynard Keynes, Levy proposes a theory of the economy that is open to rich empirical and historical scrutiny, covering topics that include the emergence of capitalism, the notion of radical uncertainty, the meaning of demand, the primal desire for money, the history of corporations, and contemporary globalization. Writing for anyone interested in the study of the economy, Levy provides an invaluable provocation for a broader debate in the social sciences and humanities concerning what “the economy” is.

“Few historians have such a thorough understanding of the development of American capitalism. The extensive knowledge and critical perspective that emerge from these writings will provide a unique and indispensable contribution to the debate.The book is one of-a kind.”—Francesco Boldizzoni, Norwegian University of Science and Technology

“Levy has an admirable ability to distill difficult economic theories to their essence, evaluate their usefulness, and then find historical applications. He does not simply point out shortcomings. Instead, he resuscitates ideas, concepts, and theories from the past that were lost on the cutting-room floor as neoclassical economics was formalized. The book will serve as an inspiration and guide to those who seek to develop new categories and theoretical frameworks designed to grapple with the ‘real economy.’”—Carl Wennerlind, Barnard College

Stay connected for new books and special offers. Subscribe to receive a welcome discount for your next order. 

  • ebook & Audiobook Cart

IMAGES

  1. Ch08 all macro__lecture_ppt

    geography hypothesis economics

  2. How to Write a Hypothesis in 12 Steps 2023

    geography hypothesis economics

  3. (PDF) Economic Geography: A Contemporary Introduction

    geography hypothesis economics

  4. Hypothesis testing in Statistics Geography

    geography hypothesis economics

  5. Environmental Kuznets curve

    geography hypothesis economics

  6. What Is The Link Between Economics And Geography?

    geography hypothesis economics

VIDEO

  1. WAGNER'S HYPOTHESIS (VI SEM BA ECONOMICS QUESTION PAPER DISCUSSION)

  2. ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY GRADE 12 PART 1

  3. EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS

  4. Permanent Income Hypothesis

  5. Nebular hypothesis || Geography || JTET MAINS || || Paper 4 || Class 6-8

  6. The Origin and Evolution of Earth #Geography(foundation)#UPSC#APSC#Early Theory #Nabular hypothesis

COMMENTS

  1. The Effect of Geography and Institutions on Economic Development: The

    The crux of the geography hypothesis is the positive relationship between access to natural resources and economic performance. The availability of certain environmental components is considered a prerequisite for economic development, whereas the lack of them is claimed to hinder or even preclude progress.

  2. Economic geography

    Economic geography is the subfield of human geography that studies economic activity and factors affecting it. ... ethnic economies, gendered economies, core-periphery theory, the economics of urban form, the relationship between the environment and the economy (tying into a long history of geographers studying culture-environment interaction), ...

  3. Economic Geography and Trade

    Geography matters for trade, and trade matters for shaping economic geography. To capture this a theory of location of economic activity is needed. Classical trade theory offers a theory, but, as noted earlier, its assumptions proved too restrictive to provide insight into many important phenomena. In particular, the rise in the volume of intra ...

  4. Development, Geography, and Economic Theory

    Economic geography seems to have fared even worse, as economists shied away from grappling with questions about space—such as the size, location, or even existence of cities—because the "terrain was seen as unsuitable for the tools at hand." Krugman's book, however, is not a call to abandon economic modeling.

  5. PDF The New Introduction to Geographical Economics

    1 A first look at geography, trade, and development 3 1.1 Introduction 3 1.2 Clustering and the world economy 4 1.3 Economic interaction 14 1.4 Rapid change in the distribution of production and population 21 1.5 Overview of the book 26 Appendix 28 Exercises 31 2 Geography and economic theory 32 2.1 Introduction 32

  6. The new economic geography: Past, present and the future

    F: Well, historically speaking, both the new economic geography and non- monocentric urban models represent a renewed interest in the “general theory of location and space economy†, using the terminology of Isard (1956), or in short, the general location theory, which is supposed to embrace “the total spatial array of economic ...

  7. The Emergence of Geographical Economics: at The Contested Boundaries of

    Economic geography, as studied by geographers, had already taken a quantitative and theoretical turn in the 1960s, reviving an earlier tradition of German location theory overshadowed within geography after World War II by areal differentiation.

  8. Journal of Economic Geography

    The aims of the Journal of Economic Geography are to redefine and reinvigorate the intersection between economics and geography, and to provide a world-class journal in the field. The journal is steered by a distinguished team of Editors and an Editorial Board, drawn equally from the two disciplines. It publishes original academic research and discussion of the highest scholarly standard in ...

  9. Economic Geography

    Quantitative Economic Geography. Eric Sheppard, Paul Plummer, in International Encyclopedia of Human Geography (Second Edition), 2020. Abstract. Quantitative economic geography (the use of mathematics to advance propositions about the nature of the spatial economy and statistical analysis of spatial economic data) emerged in economic geography through research on location theory and spatial ...

  10. Introduction Economic Geography in the Twenty-first Century

    The project also focuses on the impacts of finance on regional development. Dariusz is a member of the editorial board of Economic Geography, the Journal of Economic Geography, Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space and GeoJournal and leads the Global Network on Financial Geography (FinGeo).

  11. Economic geography: a critical introduction

    First, and most innovatively, the authors cast a critical gaze onto economic geography itself throughout the first section. Roughly 60% of the text, the section includes chapters on the scope and history of the discipline, the use (and abuse) of theory, and methods for doing economic geography.

  12. Geography, economic structures and institutions: A synthesis

    By geography we mean those natural factors (climate, temperature, soil fertility) that affect economic outcomes ( Sachs, 2001, Khemraj, 2015) and institutions refer to the humanly devised constraints that structure political, economic, and social interaction ( North, 1991 ). We define economic structures as the aggregate representation of a ...

  13. PDF Geography and Economic Development

    Geography and Economic Development John Luke Gallup and Jeffrey D. Sachs, with Andrew D. Mellinger* Abstract This paper addresses the complex relationship between geography and macroeconomic growth. We investigate the ways in which geography may matter directly for growth, controlling for economic policies and institutions, as well

  14. Economic Geography

    Economic Geography is an internationally peer-reviewed journal committed to publishing original research that makes leading-edge advances within and beyond the sub-discipline of economic geography. We publish high-quality, substantive work that is theoretically rich and informed by empirical evidence that deepens our understandings of the geographical drivers and implications of economic ...

  15. Geography, nature, and the question of development

    Morishima M (1973) Marx's Economics: A Dual Theory of Value and Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar. Muthu S (2003 ... Gertler M, Feldman M (eds) Handbook of Economic Geography. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 199-219. Google Scholar. Sheppard E (2002) The spaces and times of globalization: Place, scale, networks ...

  16. Rethinking (New) Economic Geography Models: Taking Geography and

    Abstract. Two aspects of New Economic Geography models are often singled out for criticism, especially by geographers: the treatment of geography, typically as a pre-given, fixed and highly idealized abstract geometric space; and the treatment of history, typically as 'logical' time (the movement to equilibrium in a model's solution space) rather than real history.

  17. Full article: Economic Geography: A Critical Introduction

    Economic Geography: A Critical Introduction offers a lasting contribution not just to describing economic geography's past and present, ... There is theory, but it is (usually) attuned to diversity, discrepancy, unintended consequences, and accident. Things come together not mechanically like the inner workings of a Swiss watch, but messily ...

  18. Understanding Prosperity and Poverty: Geography, Institutions, and the

    In this chapter, we argue that differences in institutions are more important than geography for understanding the divergent economic and social conditions of nations. While the geography hypothesis emphasizes forces of nature as a primary factor in the poverty of nations, the institutions hypothesis is about man-made influences. According to ...

  19. PDF Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the

    geography hypothesis. More sophisticated versions of this hypothesis focus on the time-varying effects of geography. Certain geographic character-istics that were not useful, or even harmful, for successful eco-nomic performance in 1500 may turn out to be bene"cial later on. A possible example, which we call"the temperate drift hypothe-

  20. Theoretical economic geography and spatial econometrics ...

    Theoretical economic geography has received significant new impetus from so. called 'new economic geography' theory, and this provides the basis of the spatial econometric model developed in this paper. The model, which is seen. as part of an attempt to bridge the gap that presently exists between this new.

  21. Journal of Economic Geography

    C12 - Hypothesis Testing: General; C14 - Semiparametric and Nonparametric Methods: General; ... The Journal of Economic Geography welcomes Special Issue Proposals that fit with the interdisciplinary journal's aims and scope and significantly contribute to current debates and research in economic geography, ...

  22. Development, Geography, and Economic Theory

    by Paul Krugman. Paperback. $30.00. Paperback. ISBN: 9780262611350. Pub date: August 21, 1997. Publisher: The MIT Press. 127 pp., 5 x 8 in, MIT Press Bookstore Penguin Random House Amazon Barnes and Noble Bookshop.org Indiebound Indigo Books a Million.

  23. Research Guides: Human Geography: Economic geography

    A world made for money: economy, geography, and the way we live today by Bret Wallach. Call Number: eBook. ISBN: 9780803298910. A spirited and incisive survey of economic geography, A World Made for Money begins with the author stopped at a red light in Norman, Oklahoma.

  24. The Real Economy

    Drawing inspiration particularly from Thorstein Veblen and John Maynard Keynes, Levy proposes a theory of the economy that is open to rich empirical and historical scrutiny, covering topics that include the emergence of capitalism, the notion of radical uncertainty, the meaning of demand, the primal desire for money, the history of corporations ...